Blog Post

Germany’s post-pandemic current account surplus

The pandemic has increased the net lending position of the German corporate sector. By incentivising private investment, policymakers could trigger a virtuous cycle of increasing wages, decreasing corporate net lending, which would eventually lead to a reduction of the economy-wide current account surplus.

By: and Date: October 21, 2021 Topic: European governance

In 2019, Germany ran a current account surplus of $290 billion, the largest in the world. Germany’s current account surplus is persistently large: from 2011 to 2020, it never dropped below 6% of GDP and remained above 7% for six consecutive years (from 2014 to 2019, see Figure 1). Such levels are highly unusual for a country in the western world as was pointed out back in 2018.

As a consequence, Germany’s international investment position (the difference between the external financial assets and liabilities of residents of a given country) has consistently increased over the same period, reaching €2.1 trillion in the second quarter of 2021 or 61% of GDP.

Much of the current account increase is due to the corporate sector

Looking at a sector-level breakdown of the economy-wide net lending position (Table 1) provides information on the sectoral composition of the increase in the current account balance. From 1998 to 2016 (the year with the largest current account surplus position as a % of GDP), the economy’s total net lending position (as a % of GDP) increased by 9.4 percentage points. The increase in this period was due to increases in the non-financial corporate sector (+ 3.4 pp) and general government (+3.8 pp) and to a lesser extent households’ net lending position (+1.8 pp). This somewhat contradicts the often-stated claims that Germany’s current account surplus has been driven by thrifty households. The increase in the corporate sector is particularly unusual, resulting in it becoming a net-provider of funds to the economy (companies are usually net borrowers).

The increase in the corporate net lending is a result of both, an increase in corporate savings (Jüppner (2021)[1]) and a decrease in investments.

[1] Jüppner, Marcus (2021) “Determinants of Corporate Savings in Germany” Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik

Between 2016 and 2019, the unusual situation of having a strong net-lending corporate sector changed notably, with the net lending position of non-financial corporations falling from 2.4 to 0.3% of GDP due in part to a pickup of investment in the manufacturing sector and a fall in the sector’s net savings.

The pandemic had a negative impact on corporate investment and household borrowing. This resulted in a sharp increase in the net lending position of both non-financial corporations (+2pp) and households (+3.5pp).  Conversely, the net lending position of the General government decreased by 5.8 pp in a single year. In other words, government measures were strong enough to more than offset the increase in net lending of the private sector, resulting in a slight decrease in the total economy’s net lending position (-0.8pp).

What is more surprising is that, according to AMECO forecasts, the net lending position of the corporate sector is set to remain very high in 2022, hinting that the unusual situation of net lending companies in 2016 could, in fact, be the new norm in the German economy. Could this indicate that the 2016-2019 pickup in corporate fixed capital formation was only temporary? Notably, preliminary numbers from the Federal Statistical Office indicate that capital formation for machinery and equipment in the entire economy during the first two quarters of 2021 remains below pre-pandemic levels (Figure 2).

An overall lack in investment

The overall low level of investment by the corporate sector in Germany has already been the subject of a previous blog post. The growth of the real net capital stock since the beginning of European monetary union in 1999 has been very slow in Germany (23%) compared to the United States (69%) or France (47%). Over the past couple of years, nothing indicates Germany is catching up with the growth rates of peers (Figure 3).

For example, in the manufacturing sector, Germany has been investing significantly less (as a share of value added) than France, Italy or the United States throughout most of monetary union (Figure 4). Despite a notable increase in the years leading up to the pandemic (2.4pp between 2016 and 2019), post-pandemic numbers and forecasts mentioned above suggest that such an increase may only have been transitory. Meanwhile, investments in the services sector have remained flat in recent years.

When breaking the numbers down by type of investment, investment in intangible capital has been significantly weaker in Germany than in France or the US and slightly lower than in Italy. Despite a very slight increase between 2013 (9.9% of value added) and 2016 (10.3%), investment in intangible capital does not seem to be picking up.

Conclusions

As talks to form a ‘traffic light’ coalition continue, it is crucial that policy makers do not lose sight of the critical importance of private sector investment to the German economy. An important reason for the high and often criticised current account surplus is insufficient corporate investments. As employment grew substantially, capital investments did not keep up leading to a stagnating capital-labour ratio. The relatively muted wage developments in Germany compared with peers may partly reflect lack of investment dynamics, which ceteris paribus should raise labour productivity. The incoming German government should reflect on how it can ensure increasing investments, especially in the corporate sector. Measures to incentivise investments in intangible capital should be considered. The incoming German government thus has an opportunity to trigger a virtuous cycle between increasing investments, higher minimum wages, lower corporate net lending and eventually a falling current account surplus. That virtuous cycle could be triggered by a combination of improving investment conditions and modernising the German infrastructure on the one hand and higher minimum wages on the other.

Recommended citation:

Guetta-Jeanrenaud, L. and G. Wolff (2021) ‘Germany’s post-pandemic current account surplus’, Bruegel Blog, 21 October


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

Green public investment after COVID-19

How can the public sector meet the climate funding needs of the EU?

Speakers: Zsolt Darvas, Elena Flores, Louise Skouby and Laurent Zylberberg Topic: Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: July 5, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

BRI 2.0: How has the pandemic influenced China’s landmark Belt and Road Initiative?

China's Belt and Road Initiative is undergoing a transformation after two years of pandemic. How is it changing and what are the consequences for Europe.

Speakers: Alessia Amighini, Eyck Freymann, Alicia García-Herrero and Zhang Xiaotong Topic: Global economy and trade Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: June 23, 2022
Read article More by this author
 

Blog Post

European governance

Discretion lets Croatia in but leaves Bulgaria out of the euro area in 2023

Crucial decisions about whether a country can join the euro area depend on questionable discretionary decisions.

By: Zsolt Darvas Topic: European governance, Macroeconomic policy Date: June 22, 2022
Read article Download PDF
 

External Publication

European governanceEuropean Parliament

Fragmentation risk in the euro area: no easy way out for the European Central Bank

The ECB should design a specific tool that will accompany interest rate hikes to neutralise the risk of fragmentation directly for countries facing it, staying within the bounds of the EU treaties and ensuring political legitimacy. We also advocate structural changes to the ECB’s collateral framework to avoid unnecessary uncertainty surrounding the safe asset status of European sovereign bonds.

By: Maria Demertzis, Grégory Claeys and Lionel Guetta-Jeanrenaud Topic: European governance, European Parliament, Testimonies Date: June 8, 2022
Read article More by this author
 

Opinion

European governance

Three headaches for the European Central Bank

Even though inflation in the euro area is lower than in the US, three issues make it a lot more difficult for the ECB to control inflation and preserve financial stability. Once again, the limits of EMU architecture are visible and will require a rethink.

By: Maria Demertzis Topic: European governance, Macroeconomic policy Date: May 31, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Podcast

Podcast

Taming inflation?

What are the implications of prolonged inflation?

By: The Sound of Economics Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 25, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

What is in store for Euro area economies?

ECB Executive Board Member Philip Lane discusses the outlook for Euro area economies.

Speakers: Maria Demertzis and Philip Lane Topic: European governance Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: May 5, 2022
Read article More by this author
 

Blog Post

Owning up to sustainability risks: the EU should champion international standards

To keep European Union capital markets open and integrated, new international standards should be reflected in future European law and accounting practice to provide further incentives for a reallocation of capital, reflecting in particular climate risks.

By: Alexander Lehmann Topic: Banking and capital markets, Green economy Date: April 26, 2022
Read article Download PDF More on this topic
 

Working Paper

The low productivity of European firms: how can policies enhance the allocation of resources?

A summary of the most important policy lessons from research undertaken in the MICROPROD project work package 4, related to the allocation of the factors of production, with a special focus on the weak dynamism of European small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).

By: Grégory Claeys, Marie Le Mouel and Giovanni Sgaravatti Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 25, 2022
Read article Download PDF More on this topic
 

Working Paper

Knowledge flows and global value chains

Trade and industrial policy can support productivity growth through global value chains by providing the right legal environment that supports the formation of longterm business relationships.

By: Marta Bisztray and Niclas Poitiers Topic: Global economy and trade Date: April 13, 2022
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

Is the private sector retreating in China? Not among its largest companies

Though private ownership does not free companies from the pervasive influence of the Communist Party, China’s private and state sectors are not equivalent; China’s largest firms are growing faster than their state-owned counterparts.

By: Tianlei Huang and Nicolas Véron Topic: Global economy and trade Date: April 5, 2022
Read article Download PDF More on this topic
 

Working Paper

The private sector advances in China: The evolving ownership structures of the largest companies in the Xi Jinping era

This paper documents recent structural changes in China’s corporate landscape, based on company level data, providing a complementary perspective to that of official Chinese statistics.

By: Tianlei Huang and Nicolas Véron Topic: Global economy and trade Date: April 5, 2022
Load more posts