Blog Post

Blogs review: Asset prices and monetary policy redux

What’s at stake: Federal Reserve Governor Jeremy Stein gave serious consideration to the idea that monetary policy has a role to play in managing financial stability (read asset prices) in a speech titled “Overheating in Credit Markets: Origins, Measurement, and Policy Responses” given last week at a conference hosted by the St. Louis Fed. Governor Stein provided evidence that risk was building in certain segments of financial markets and discussed policy tools that go beyond countercyclical macroprudential regulation or the simple use of the Federal Funds rate to address these risks.

By: and Date: February 15, 2013 Topic: Global economy and trade

What’s at stake: Federal Reserve Governor Jeremy Stein gave serious consideration to the idea that monetary policy has a role to play in managing financial stability (read asset prices) in a speech titled “Overheating in Credit Markets: Origins, Measurement, and Policy Responses” given last week at a conference hosted by the St. Louis Fed. Governor Stein provided evidence that risk was building in certain segments of financial markets and discussed policy tools that go beyond countercyclical macroprudential regulation or the simple use of the Federal Funds rate to address these risks.

Questioning the Greenspan-Bernanke orthodoxy

Free Exchange writes that before the crisis, monetary policymakers generally agreed that they should not concern themselves with financial stability until after something bad had already happened. Prevention was the job of the regulators, they said. Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler made the most comprehensive case for this hands-off approach in 1999. A few dissented, such as the Bank for International Settlements’ dynamic duo of Claudio Borio and William White, as well as Raghuram Rajan of the University of Chicago. But the establishment mostly ignored them until the crisis.

Neil Irwin writes at the Wonkblog that it’s good to see leaders of the Fed grappling—in their cerebral, cautious way, at least—with an issue that has seemed apparent to many in financial markets for years: That low interest rate policies and unconventional easing programs such as Fed bond purchases can have hard-to-predict results throughout the financial system beyond those that traditional models of how monetary policy affects the economy would predict.

The incentives of financial intermediaries and the search for yield

Governor Jeremy Stein argued that a change in the economic environment that alters the risk-taking incentives of agents making credit decisions could lead to overheating. For example, a prolonged period of low interest rates, of the sort we are experiencing today, can create incentives for agents to take on greater duration or credit risks, or to employ additional financial leverage, in an effort to “reach for yield.” If the underlying economic environment creates a strong incentive for financial institutions to, say, take on more credit risk in a reach for yield, it is unlikely that regulatory tools can completely contain this behavior.

Gavyn Davies writes that the speech argues that the credit markets have recently been “reaching for yield”, much as they did prior to the financial crash. Although not yet as dangerous as in the period from 2004-2007, this behavior is shown by the rapid expansion of the junk bond market (see Figure), flows into high-yield mutual funds and real estate investment trusts and the duration of bond portfolios held by banks. Governor Jeremy Stein argues that overheating in the junk bond market although not a major systemic concern in and of itself might indicate that similar overheating forces are at play in other parts of credit markets, out of our range of vision.

Source: Jeremy Stein

Policy implications: principles and historical precedents

Governor Jeremy Stein argues that as we move forward, and assuming that the trends in asset-liability mismatch identified continue, it will be important to keep an open mind and avoid adhering to the decoupling philosophy – that monetary policy should restrict its attention to the dual mandate goals of price stability and maximum employment, while the full battery of supervisory and regulatory tools should be used to safeguard financial stability – too rigidly. While monetary policy may not be quite the right tool for the job, it has one important advantage relative to supervision and regulation–namely that it gets in all of the cracks. The one thing that a commercial bank, a broker-dealer, an offshore hedge fund, and a special purpose vehicle have in common is that they all face the same set of market interest rates.

Scott Sumner wonders how much Mr. Stein knows about Fed policy during the 1920s.  The paper does not mention that 1929 was the last time the Fed tried to implement his proposed policy. During the 1920s NY Fed President Benjamin Strong was under a lot of pressure to “do something” about the stock market boom.  He resisted, arguing the Fed should focus on stabilizing prices and output. He died in August 1928, and the new leaders of the Fed finally had their chance.  They raised interest rates in late 1928, and then in early 1929, and then in mid-1929.  By the late summer of 1929 short-term rates were at 6%.  Recall that this was a very high real rate, as there was deflation during the 1927-29 business cycle expansion, despite the fact that the economy was booming. Finally money got so tight that the economy tipped into depression.  And it was (expectations of) the depression that caused the stock market crash, not the high interest rates.

Berkeley PhD student Carola Binder writes in her new blog Quantitative Ease that the Fed also regarded bubbles as the most likely negative consequence of its efforts to reduce unemployment by stimulating growth in 1953-54. In 1955, as the economy was recovering, the minutes from the Federal Open Market Committee refer multiple times to concerns about "speculative developments" or "speculative excesses." The March 2 minutes note: “The critical problem for credit and monetary policy in the United States was […] how to thread its way along the narrow ledge that encourages sound economic growth and high employment and, at the same time, limits speculative developments and discourages financial over commitments by businesses and consumers.”

Ryan Avent writes that we should not let the lessons of the last disaster obscure the lessons of the ones that came before.

In a 2010 paper for the BIS titled "the changing role of central banks", Charles Goodhart argues that the question is not whether a Central Bank that sets interest rates should also manage financial stability but whether a Central Bank that manages both liquidity and financial stability should also be given the task of setting interest rates. Unlike the essential role of liquidity management, setting official interest rates is not essential for a Central Bank. In history many central banks did not set interest rates and this task was left to the government or to an external committee.

Charles Goodhart argues that in the 19th century, the BoE had an intellectual framework that dealt with the trade-off between price stability and financial stability. It was the real bills doctrine. So long as discounts and lending were strongly directed to ‘real bills’, both price stability and financial stability were supposed to be jointly and simultaneously assured. The "real bills " led to mistakes and policy failures during the interwar but "ever since this Victorian era we have lacked such a unifying theory. So now we wonder whether the single interest rate instrument can, or should, be made to bear double duty, to ‘lean into the wind’ of asset price and credit fluctuations as well as stabilizing inflation, and its expectations".

Policy proposal: changing the composition of asset holding even after the ZLB

Governor Jeremy Stein has a particular proposal in response to concerns about numbers of instruments. We have seen in recent years that the monetary policy toolkit consists of more than just a single instrument. We can do more than adjust the federal funds rate. By changing the composition of our asset holdings, as in our recently completed maturity extension program (MEP), we can influence not just the expected path of short rates, but also term premiums and the shape of the yield curve. Once we move away from the zero lower bound, this second instrument might continue to be helpful, not simply in providing accommodation, but also as a complement to other efforts on the financial stability front.

John Cochrane argues that once the central bank does something else than setting interest rates and conducing open market operations, the risk to interfere and distort markets is high. Cochrane argues that an agency that allocates credit to specific markets and institutions, or buys assets that expose taxpayers to risks, cannot stay independent of elected, and accountable, officials.

Also of note is a 2012 paper Jeremy Stein where the author models the market imperfection that leads to the need of central bank’s intervention to maintain financial stability. When banks issue cheaper short-term debt, they capture the social benefits (liquidity for households) but do not fully internalize the costs (fire sales in case of adverse shocks) of such actions. The author favors a  “cap-and-trade” system in which banks are granted tradable permits, each of which allows them to do some amount of money creation.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

It’s hard to live in the city: Berlin’s rent freeze and the economics of rent control

A proposal in Berlin to ban increases in rent for the next five years sparked intense debate in Germany. Similar policies to the Mietendeckel are currently being discussed in London and NYC. All three proposals reflect and raise similar concerns – the increase in per-capita incomes is not keeping pace with increases in rents, but will a cap do more harm than good? We review recent views on the matter.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: July 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The breakdown of the covered interest rate parity condition

A textbook condition of international finance breaks down. Economic research identifies the interplay between divergent monetary policies and new financial regulation as the source of the puzzle, and generates concerns about unintended consequences for financing conditions and financial stability.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Bruegel Topic: Banking and capital markets Date: July 1, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The June Eurogroup meeting: Reflections on BICC

The Eurogroup met on June 13th to discuss the deepening of the economic and monetary union (EMU) and prepare the discussions for the Euro Summit. From the meeting came two main deliverables: an agreement over a budgetary instrument for competitiveness and convergence and the reform of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) treaty texts. We review economists’ first impressions.

By: Bruegel and Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: June 24, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The campaign against ‘nonsense’ output gaps

A campaign against “nonsense” consensus output gaps has been launched on social media. It has triggered responses focusing on the implications of output gaps for fiscal policy under EU rules, especially for Italy. But the debate about the reliability of output-gap estimates is more wide-ranging.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Bruegel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: June 17, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The inverted yield curve

Longer-term yields falling below shorter-term yields have historically preceded recessions. Last week, the US 10-year yield was 21 basis points below the 3-month yield, a feat last seen during the summer of 2007. Is the current yield curve a trustworthy barometer for future growth?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Global economy and trade Date: June 11, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The 'seven' ceiling: China's yuan in trade talks

Investors and the public have been looking at the renminbi with caution after the Trump administration threatened to increase duties on countries that intervene in the markets to devalue/undervalue their currency relative to the dollar. The fear is that China could weaponise its currency following the further increase in tariffs imposed by the United States in early May. What is the likelihood of this happening and what would be the consequences for the existing tensions with the United States, as well as for the global economy?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Global economy and trade Date: June 3, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The next ECB president

On May 28th, EU heads of state and government will start the nomination process for the next ECB president. Leaving names of possible candidates aside, this review tries to isolate the arguments about what qualifications the new president should have and what challenges he or she is likely to face.

By: Bruegel and Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 27, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

The latest European growth-rate estimates

The quarterly growth rate of the euro area in Q1 2019 was 0.4% (1.5% annualized), considerably higher than the low growth rates of the previous two quarters. This blog reviews the reaction to the release of these numbers and the discussion they have triggered about the euro area’s economic challenges.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 20, 2019
Read article More by this author
 

Blog Post

Is an electric car a cleaner car?

An article published by the Ifo Institute in Germany compares the carbon footprint of a battery-electric car to that of a diesel car, and argues a higher share of electric cars will not contribute to reducing German carbon dioxide emissions. Respondents rejected the authors’ calculations as unrealistic and biased, and pointed to a series of studies that conclude the opposite. We summarise the article and responses to it.

By: Michael Baltensperger Topic: Digital economy and innovation, Green economy Date: May 13, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

All eyes on the Fed

Last week the US Federal Reserve left the federal funds rate unchanged and lowered the interest rate on excess reserves. We review economists’ recent views on the monetary policy conduct and priorities of the United States’ central bank system.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Global economy and trade Date: May 6, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

Is this blog post legal (under new EU copyright law)?

How new EU rules on using snippets from news publishers and on copyright infringement liability might affect circulation of information, revenue distribution, market power and EU business competitiveness.

By: Catarina Midões Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

Secular stagnation and the future of economic stabilisation

Larry Summers’ and Łukasz Rachel’s most recent study documents a secular fall in neutral real rates in advanced economies. According to the authors, this fall would be even more marked in the absence of offsetting fiscal policies. Policymaking in a world of permanently low interest rates may be hard to navigate, especially in troubled waters. We review economists’ views on the matter

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 1, 2019
Load more posts