Blog Post

Bubbles and potential output

What’s at stake: What started as a speech on inflation targeting by the President of a regional Fed has turned into a fierce economic debate on the impact of the collapse of a bubble on potential GDP. While it is natural for the current debate to focus on this phase of the problem, a growing literature has also explored the impact of bubbles on potential GDP during the boom phase. We start by reviewing the provocative body of work that studies bubbles in the presence of financial frictions, which often come to the conclusion that bubbles can increase potential output by reducing the inefficiency induced by financial market frictions. We then review the current debate on the econ blogosphere following the infamous Bullard speech. Although the arguments are somewhat decoupled from the ones we outline in the first part and focus on more familiar ideas, it is interesting to see that a Fed regional President played by the rules of the econ blogosphere and wrote his own “geeky” post as a response to the criticisms he had received.

By: and Date: February 17, 2012 Topic: Global economy and trade

In the boom years

As in many recent strands of the macro literature – think of the debate on balance sheet recessions – the body of work that studies bubbles in the presence of financial frictions emphasizes the importance of distributional concerns for the macroeconomy by studying the kind of transfers that bubbles implement.

In a voxEU contribution, Alberto Martin and Jaume Ventura provide some useful background on the theory of rational bubbles. Samuelson (1958) and Tirole (1985) laid the foundations for such a theory by portraying bubbles as a remedy to the problem of dynamic inefficiency. Their argument is based on the dual role of capital as a productive asset and a store of value. To satisfy the need for a store of value, economies sometimes accumulate so much capital that the investment required to sustain it exceeds the income that it produces. This investment is inefficient and lowers the resources available for consumption. In this situation, bubbles can be both attractive to investors and feasible from a macroeconomic perspective. For instance, a pyramid scheme that absorbs all inefficient investments in each period is feasible and its return exceeds that of the investments it replaces. The Samuelson-Tirole model provides an elegant and powerful framework to think about bubbles. However, the picture that emerges from this theory is hard to reconcile with historical evidence. In the Samuelson-Tirole model bubbles raise consumption by reducing inefficient investments. As a result, bubbles slow down capital accumulation and lower output. In the real world, however, bubbly episodes tend to be associated with both consumption booms and expansions in the capital stock.

In a set of related papers Alberto Martin and Jaume Ventura investigate mechanisms through which bubbles can increase potential output. The starting observation for both papers is quite simple: Bubbles not only reduce inefficient investments, but also increase efficient ones. In the first paper – an OLG model with productive and unproductive agents – bubbles induce two kinds of transfers: an intergenational transfer, which is welfare reducing as it reduces consumption and capital accumulation by the youngs; and an intragenerational transfer, which helps mitigate the effects of financial frictions (to model financial frictions, the authors simply assume that the unproductive guys cannot lend to the productive guys). During bubbly episodes, unproductive investors demand bubbles while productive investors supply them. These transfers of resources improve the efficiency at which the economy operates, expanding consumption, the capital stock and output. In the second paper, bubbles may also transfer resources towards efficient investments through the credit market. This happens when the prospect of a future bubble raises the net worth of efficient investors, therefore allowing them to expand their borrowing and investment.

After the collapse: investigating the Bullard story

David Andolfatto gives some background on the infamous speech. This speech is really about how to interpret the recent performance of the U.S. economy. Is the conventional interpretation, that we are far below “potential” GDP owing to “deficient demand,” the correct view? Or should we instead be thinking in terms of a large negative shock to “potential” GDP, with unemployment returning slowly to its natural rate, according to its normal dynamic?

More interesting than the initial speech – which, because of poorly argued statements gave rise to the initial outcry by bloggers – is Jim Bullard’s “geeky” response to bloggers. In this text, Bullard argues that potential output – as currently measured by the CBO – does not correct for output growth driven by sunspot equilibriums. Because this drove some of the growth in the 2000s, the current output gap even by a production function metric would be smaller since the widespread belief that sustained this sunspot equilibrium – that “house prices never fall” – will not and should not return. So it is not that the bubble destroyed potential, instead it is that actual output was higher than properly defined potential during the mid-2000s, and then it crashed back as the bubble burst.

Tim Duy looks more closely at the CBO estimate and sees two recent episodes of output in excess of CBO potential, both of which were associated with what the author believes were asset-price bubbles.  Furthermore, if this was a significant overestimate of potential output in during the housing bubble, we would have expected more severe inflationary pressures. At the core of Bullard’s asset-bubble model of potential GDP shifts it is a demand story with maybe a second-order labor supply aspect. This sounds quantitatively irrelevant and does not explain why no other source of demand can compensate for the lost housing bubble and induce higher labor supply.

Paul Krugman argues that Bullard changed positions following the flood of online commentary. In the first version, Bullard seemed to be arguing that the wealth loss from the burst bubble represented a real destruction of economic capacity. Now he seems to be making a quite different case: that the economy in 2005-2007 was operating at an unsustainably high rate of capacity utilization, driven by the bubble. Krugman likes Bullard’s new version better than the old one, but it’s still wrong. Demand in the mid-naughties was not, in fact, at fever pitch. Yes, we had very residential construction and high consumer spending. But we also had record-high trade deficits, so that overall demand wasn’t that vigorous, after all.

Scott Sumner also notes that although everyone agrees that housing construction was too high in 2004-06.  But that doesn’t mean RGDP was too high.  After all, the resources that went into housing could have come at the expense of other sectors. How about SRAS?  Bullard mentions a rise in labor supply caused by the housing bubble, but I don’t see the logic.  What would be evidence for a rise in labor supply?  Presumably you’d see unusual patterns in the employment to population ratio during the 2000s, but I just don’t see it.  His best argument would be that the desire to work had been dropping sharply for many years, and that this increased preference for leisure was temporarily covered up by a housing bubble that mysterious caused people to want to work more.  Then when they found they could no longer build houses, they decided they didn’t want to work at all.  They didn’t like other jobs being offered.

Potential output, flexible price output, and trend output

In his post, Jim Bullard notes that the different definitions of potential output make the discussion blurry. Bullard argues that the terms of the debate should be based on the appropriate definition of the output gap according to the available New Keynesian literature: that the output gap is the distance between the actual level of output under sticky prices and the flexible price level of output. For that matter, the flexible price level of output would fluctuate continuously in response to shocks hitting the economy. Tim Duy argues that somewhere in the background there is need for some structural change, toward export and import competing industries.  That said, it is hard to believe that this is the primary story given that the downturn negatively affected employment across almost all industries.  If structural adjustment was the primary issue, I would have anticipated a narrower range of affected industries.

Menzie Chinn had a useful post a few months ago where he presented the difficulty of linking the concept of potential output in DSGE models with the one used for policymaking. DSGEs (and their predecessors, RBCs) are models of the business cycle. As such, they focus on the deviations from trend. However, in order to predict where the economy will be in one year, given current conditions and policies, one needs to know what the trend is. In other words, extracting the cycle from the trend is critically important. Camilo Tovar notes further that the dynamics obtained do not match those required by policy makers, weakening the usefulness of DSGE models as policy tools. For a detailed and technical discussion on some of these issues, see Gorodnichenko and Ng.

What this episode says about the American econ blogosphere

This episode illustrates the importance of the American economic blogosphere in the economic policy debate. And if you believe Paul Krugman, the blogosphere did not only manage to get a proper written response from a policymaker but basically made that person realized that part of his argument was wrong. Scott Sumner also sees this as a victory for the blogosphere, especially for Tim Duy, who was at the center of this controversy. Brad DeLong adds that it is also a victory for Mark Thoma who built “Economist’s View” into a must-visit platform and then shared that platform with Tim Duy.

Brad DeLong further notes that those of us who have wasted our time in this business over the past decade got into it because we were horrified by episodes that showed the conventional press corps engaged in extraordinary efforts to lower the level of the economic policy debate and felt that somebody, somewhere needed to try to do something constructive. The Bullard-Duy exchange is a powerful piece of evidence that we – and those of us whom the fish that the conventional news media have hired in their attempt to turn into birds, and those of our fellow travelers in the conventional press corps who kept the faith and tried to keep the cold altars lit – have to a surprising degree succeeded: our time was not, after all, wasted.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

It’s hard to live in the city: Berlin’s rent freeze and the economics of rent control

A proposal in Berlin to ban increases in rent for the next five years sparked intense debate in Germany. Similar policies to the Mietendeckel are currently being discussed in London and NYC. All three proposals reflect and raise similar concerns – the increase in per-capita incomes is not keeping pace with increases in rents, but will a cap do more harm than good? We review recent views on the matter.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: July 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The breakdown of the covered interest rate parity condition

A textbook condition of international finance breaks down. Economic research identifies the interplay between divergent monetary policies and new financial regulation as the source of the puzzle, and generates concerns about unintended consequences for financing conditions and financial stability.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Bruegel Topic: Banking and capital markets Date: July 1, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The June Eurogroup meeting: Reflections on BICC

The Eurogroup met on June 13th to discuss the deepening of the economic and monetary union (EMU) and prepare the discussions for the Euro Summit. From the meeting came two main deliverables: an agreement over a budgetary instrument for competitiveness and convergence and the reform of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) treaty texts. We review economists’ first impressions.

By: Bruegel and Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: June 24, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The campaign against ‘nonsense’ output gaps

A campaign against “nonsense” consensus output gaps has been launched on social media. It has triggered responses focusing on the implications of output gaps for fiscal policy under EU rules, especially for Italy. But the debate about the reliability of output-gap estimates is more wide-ranging.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Bruegel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: June 17, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The inverted yield curve

Longer-term yields falling below shorter-term yields have historically preceded recessions. Last week, the US 10-year yield was 21 basis points below the 3-month yield, a feat last seen during the summer of 2007. Is the current yield curve a trustworthy barometer for future growth?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Global economy and trade Date: June 11, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The 'seven' ceiling: China's yuan in trade talks

Investors and the public have been looking at the renminbi with caution after the Trump administration threatened to increase duties on countries that intervene in the markets to devalue/undervalue their currency relative to the dollar. The fear is that China could weaponise its currency following the further increase in tariffs imposed by the United States in early May. What is the likelihood of this happening and what would be the consequences for the existing tensions with the United States, as well as for the global economy?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Global economy and trade Date: June 3, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The next ECB president

On May 28th, EU heads of state and government will start the nomination process for the next ECB president. Leaving names of possible candidates aside, this review tries to isolate the arguments about what qualifications the new president should have and what challenges he or she is likely to face.

By: Bruegel and Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 27, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

The latest European growth-rate estimates

The quarterly growth rate of the euro area in Q1 2019 was 0.4% (1.5% annualized), considerably higher than the low growth rates of the previous two quarters. This blog reviews the reaction to the release of these numbers and the discussion they have triggered about the euro area’s economic challenges.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 20, 2019
Read article More by this author
 

Blog Post

Is an electric car a cleaner car?

An article published by the Ifo Institute in Germany compares the carbon footprint of a battery-electric car to that of a diesel car, and argues a higher share of electric cars will not contribute to reducing German carbon dioxide emissions. Respondents rejected the authors’ calculations as unrealistic and biased, and pointed to a series of studies that conclude the opposite. We summarise the article and responses to it.

By: Michael Baltensperger Topic: Digital economy and innovation, Green economy Date: May 13, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

All eyes on the Fed

Last week the US Federal Reserve left the federal funds rate unchanged and lowered the interest rate on excess reserves. We review economists’ recent views on the monetary policy conduct and priorities of the United States’ central bank system.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Global economy and trade Date: May 6, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

Is this blog post legal (under new EU copyright law)?

How new EU rules on using snippets from news publishers and on copyright infringement liability might affect circulation of information, revenue distribution, market power and EU business competitiveness.

By: Catarina Midões Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

Secular stagnation and the future of economic stabilisation

Larry Summers’ and Łukasz Rachel’s most recent study documents a secular fall in neutral real rates in advanced economies. According to the authors, this fall would be even more marked in the absence of offsetting fiscal policies. Policymaking in a world of permanently low interest rates may be hard to navigate, especially in troubled waters. We review economists’ views on the matter

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 1, 2019
Load more posts