Blog Post

Taxing the 1%

What’s at stake: While the movement of the “99 percent” is receding, some of the issues it raised continue to be highly discussed in academic and policy circles. In particular, a crucial public policy question is whether governments should tax high earners more. While in previous election cycles, the narrative on inequality and the crisis […]

By: and Date: December 20, 2011 Topic: Banking and capital markets

What’s at stake: While the movement of the “99 percent” is receding, some of the issues it raised continue to be highly discussed in academic and policy circles. In particular, a crucial public policy question is whether governments should tax high earners more. While in previous election cycles, the narrative on inequality and the crisis was not completely set out, detailed proposals on how to tax the 1% have, this time, already been laid out. President Obama made, for example, clear that this issue was going to be a “defining issue” of the 2012 presidential election. This could also have implications in other advanced economies where tax policy, in a context of difficult fiscal outlooks ought to become a more debated political issue.

The Saez and al. proposals

In a Journal of Economic Perspectives article, Peter Diamond and Emmanuel Saez note that although facing an average federal income tax rate of 22.4%, the top percentile of the income distribution paid 40% of total federal individual income taxes in 2007. Taxation of very high earners is therefore a central aspect of the tax policy debate not only for equity reasons but also for revenue raising. Setting aside behavioral response for a moment, the authors argue that increasing this rate to 43.4% would be sufficient to raise revenue by 3 percentage points of GDP. Remarkably, it would still leave the after-tax income share of the top percentile more than twice as high as in 1970.

Note that this definition of optimal taxation is quite different from that of Mirrlees for whom the optimal tax is the one that maximizes economic output (ie. The one that effectively minimizes the tax wedge and the disincentives to work associated with taxation). Mirrlees and Vickrey received in the Nobel prize for this work which led them to the conclusion that the marginal tax rate should actually be quite low given the marginal productivity of high income earners.

In the article, Peter Diamond and Emmanuel Saez compute that the optimal marginal tax rate – the tax rate that maximizes revenue raising – for the top percentile is around 70% in the United States. The authors explore the path from basic research results in optimal tax theory and seek to maximize the Laffer curve of fiscal revenues for a given marginal tax rate. By taking into account limits on resources and behavioral responses to taxation, and using data on elasticity responses to taxation, the authors argue that very high earners should be subject to high and rising marginal tax rates on earnings.

In a closely connected paper, using the large database constructed with Anthony Atkinson on high incomes, Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez and Stefanie Stantcheva argue that the common story to explain the rise of inequality at the high end of the income spectrum (the infamous 1%) is wrong: it cannot be technology or globalization, because all countries have been affected by these phenomena, but only English speaking countries have experienced a major rise in inequalities. The authors note that even if the strong correlation between the reductions in top tax rates and the increases in top 1% pre-tax income shares from 1975–79 to 2004–08 was entirely due to supply-side effects – where smaller top tax rates encouraged work effort and business creation among the most talented – the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would still be 57% (it would be 83% in a model that considers the response of top income earners is also due to increased rent seeking behavior). Up until the 1970s, policymakers and public opinion considered that at the very top of the income distribution, pay increases reflected mostly greed or other socially wasteful activities rather than productive work effort. This is why they were able to set marginal tax rates as high as 80% in the US and the UK. The Reagan/Thatcher revolution has succeeded in making such top tax rate levels unthinkable since then. But after decades of increasing income concentration that has brought about mediocre growth since the 1970s and a Great Recession triggered by financial sector excesses, a rethinking of the Reagan and Thatcher revolutions is perhaps underway. The United Kingdom has, for example, already increased its top income tax rate from 40% to 50% in 2010 in part to curb top pay excesses.

Reactions to the proposals

Scott Sumner argues Saez and Diamond’s argument is based on questionable assumptions. In particular, Diamond and Saez use the argument of tax avoidance in order to favor a higher taxation of capital, but then assume that loopholes should be closed to justify a high marginal tax rate on labor income. The traditional view is that the tax on capital should be zero, because a higher rate would impose higher taxes on future consumption than current consumption, and hence lead to a sub-optimal level of savings and investment.  In response, they point out that our current tax system often allows labor income being falsely reported as capital income. But, when they consider the appropriate tax rate, S-D have no problem waving a magic stick and assuming away all tax loopholes.  Notice how both assumptions favor higher MTRs on higher incomes.

Stephen Williamson
points at the dynamic effects of high taxation: lower expected earnings lead not only to lower effort (an effect taken into account by Diamond and Saez) but also to lower human capital accumulation in the first place. Not taking into account these long-term effects would stifle long-term growth.  He also criticized the proposition of Robert Frank, in Slate, who would rather see a progressive consumption tax than an income tax. His argument is that the ‘keeping-up-with-the-Joneses’ behavior (raising one’s consumption to keep his status compared with his neighbors) leads to negative externalities. Raising consumption taxes would in the end make everyone better off by reducing the race for a better status. There again, according to Williamson, it does little to take into account dynamic effects on the labor supply. Tyler Cowen uses results on CEO compensation to explain that they do add value for their shareholders, and that the incidence of higher taxation is little known.

Nancy Folbre
points that a recent essay in The Wall Street Journal asserts that the high volatility of income at the top makes it impractical to rely on taxing it. But these concerns are overstated, the author agues, and can be easily addressed by rainy-day funds that set some revenues aside as a buffer against variation. The Tax Policy Center argues that restoring pre-1982 effective rates wouldn’t require implementing pre-1982 statutory rates. Raising the top statutory rates is one way to increase effective rates, but it’s not the only (or best) way. For instance, more modest rate increases could be supplemented by scaling back tax preferences that disproportionately benefit high-income taxpayers (like the mortgage interest deduction) and very high-income taxpayers (like the preferential rate on capital gains).

Taxing job creators

Paul Krugman argues that one important idea from Diamond and Saez is that the optimal tax rate on top earners should be the rate that maximizes the revenue collected from these top earners — full stop. Right now, the rhetoric is, however, that high-income individuals are “job creators” who must be cherished for the good they do. Brad DeLong points that the idea that the rich and powerful deserves our deference is an old one that goes back to Adam Smith not in his most famous work, The Wealth of Nations, but in his far less discussed book The Theory of Moral Sentiments. On the one hand, we don’t wish to disrupt the perfect felicity of the lifestyles of the rich and famous (to which we aspire); on the other hand, we don’t wish to add to the burdens of those who have spent their most precious possession – their time and energy – pursuing baubles. These two arguments are not consistent, but that does not matter. They both have a purchase on our thinking.

Adam Ozimek
disagrees with DeLong and Krugman and In this sense, suddenly kicked out the top argues that many high skilled, high paid workers work at moving the productivity frontier forward, and thus increasing the marginal productivity of other workers. 10% of high IQ people (or 10% most productive people, or 10% most creative people, or whatever) in the U.S would in all likelihood reduce the total output of the remaining 90% would go down. Hence affecting their incentives (throught taxation) in a way that distract these people from working, reduces our ability to push or reach or production frontier.

Inequality and elections: “This is the defining issue of our time” (Obama, Dec 2011)

Robert Reich argues that the President’s speech in Osawatomie, Kansas — where Teddy Roosevelt gave his “New Nationalism” speech in 1910 — is the most important economic speech of his presidency in terms of connecting the dots, laying out the reasons behind our economic and political crises, and asserting a willingness to take on the powerful and the privileged that have gamed the system to their advantage. For those familiar with our prior issue of the Blogs review on inequality, this extract should certainly ring a bell: “For most Americans, the basic bargain that made this country great has eroded. Long before the recession hit, hard work stopped paying off for too many people. Fewer and fewer of the folks who contributed to the success of our economy actually benefitted from that success. Those at the very top grew wealthier from their incomes and investments than ever before. But everyone else struggled with costs that were growing and paychecks that weren’t – and too many families found themselves racking up more and more debt just to keep up.”

Eduardo Porter
writes in the Sunday Review of the New-York Times that today, America is an outlier among industrial nations. Inequality in America has soared over the last 30 years, approaching and even surpassing that in many poor countries. Its distribution of income looks closer to that of Argentina than, say, Germany. For more, on the general topic of inequality, we recommend the latest interview from Five Books by Daron Acemoglu.

Clive Crook
argues that Obama is right that tax revenues need to rise, but wrong to focus so tightly on top marginal income-tax rates. In terms of the politics, a center-left party advocating higher taxes on "the rich" ought to define that term a bit more narrowly than what one Democratic party spokesman recently called the ultra-rich: a household income of $250,000. True, less than 3 per cent of households make that much at any one time – but a police officer married to a civil servant could sneak into this category. Income varies during one’s lifetime, so a far larger number have crossed the line, or will do, or hope to, during their peak earning years.

Nancy Folbre
notes that American voters have the power to increase tax revenues from millionaires and have recently done so in eight states: California, Connecticut, Hawaii, Maryland, New Jersey, New York, Oregon and Wisconsin. A detailed study of the New Jersey case, published in the National Tax Journal by Cristobal Young and Charles Varner, found little effect on millionaires’ migration from the state.

*Bruegel Economic Blogs Review is an information service that surveys external blogs. It does not survey Bruegel’s own publications, nor does it include comments by Bruegel authors.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

It’s hard to live in the city: Berlin’s rent freeze and the economics of rent control

A proposal in Berlin to ban increases in rent for the next five years sparked intense debate in Germany. Similar policies to the Mietendeckel are currently being discussed in London and NYC. All three proposals reflect and raise similar concerns – the increase in per-capita incomes is not keeping pace with increases in rents, but will a cap do more harm than good? We review recent views on the matter.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: July 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The breakdown of the covered interest rate parity condition

A textbook condition of international finance breaks down. Economic research identifies the interplay between divergent monetary policies and new financial regulation as the source of the puzzle, and generates concerns about unintended consequences for financing conditions and financial stability.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Bruegel Topic: Banking and capital markets Date: July 1, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The June Eurogroup meeting: Reflections on BICC

The Eurogroup met on June 13th to discuss the deepening of the economic and monetary union (EMU) and prepare the discussions for the Euro Summit. From the meeting came two main deliverables: an agreement over a budgetary instrument for competitiveness and convergence and the reform of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) treaty texts. We review economists’ first impressions.

By: Bruegel and Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: June 24, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The campaign against ‘nonsense’ output gaps

A campaign against “nonsense” consensus output gaps has been launched on social media. It has triggered responses focusing on the implications of output gaps for fiscal policy under EU rules, especially for Italy. But the debate about the reliability of output-gap estimates is more wide-ranging.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Bruegel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: June 17, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The inverted yield curve

Longer-term yields falling below shorter-term yields have historically preceded recessions. Last week, the US 10-year yield was 21 basis points below the 3-month yield, a feat last seen during the summer of 2007. Is the current yield curve a trustworthy barometer for future growth?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Global economy and trade Date: June 11, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The 'seven' ceiling: China's yuan in trade talks

Investors and the public have been looking at the renminbi with caution after the Trump administration threatened to increase duties on countries that intervene in the markets to devalue/undervalue their currency relative to the dollar. The fear is that China could weaponise its currency following the further increase in tariffs imposed by the United States in early May. What is the likelihood of this happening and what would be the consequences for the existing tensions with the United States, as well as for the global economy?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Global economy and trade Date: June 3, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

The next ECB president

On May 28th, EU heads of state and government will start the nomination process for the next ECB president. Leaving names of possible candidates aside, this review tries to isolate the arguments about what qualifications the new president should have and what challenges he or she is likely to face.

By: Bruegel and Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 27, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

The latest European growth-rate estimates

The quarterly growth rate of the euro area in Q1 2019 was 0.4% (1.5% annualized), considerably higher than the low growth rates of the previous two quarters. This blog reviews the reaction to the release of these numbers and the discussion they have triggered about the euro area’s economic challenges.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 20, 2019
Read article More by this author
 

Blog Post

Is an electric car a cleaner car?

An article published by the Ifo Institute in Germany compares the carbon footprint of a battery-electric car to that of a diesel car, and argues a higher share of electric cars will not contribute to reducing German carbon dioxide emissions. Respondents rejected the authors’ calculations as unrealistic and biased, and pointed to a series of studies that conclude the opposite. We summarise the article and responses to it.

By: Michael Baltensperger Topic: Digital economy and innovation, Green economy Date: May 13, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

All eyes on the Fed

Last week the US Federal Reserve left the federal funds rate unchanged and lowered the interest rate on excess reserves. We review economists’ recent views on the monetary policy conduct and priorities of the United States’ central bank system.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Global economy and trade Date: May 6, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

Is this blog post legal (under new EU copyright law)?

How new EU rules on using snippets from news publishers and on copyright infringement liability might affect circulation of information, revenue distribution, market power and EU business competitiveness.

By: Catarina Midões Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

Secular stagnation and the future of economic stabilisation

Larry Summers’ and Łukasz Rachel’s most recent study documents a secular fall in neutral real rates in advanced economies. According to the authors, this fall would be even more marked in the absence of offsetting fiscal policies. Policymaking in a world of permanently low interest rates may be hard to navigate, especially in troubled waters. We review economists’ views on the matter

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo and Bruegel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 1, 2019
Load more posts