Opinion

Central banks have been too slow in responding to higher inflation

Tackling inflation requires both monetary and fiscal policy tightening. It should be done quickly to avoid building up inflationary inertia and stagflation

By: Date: July 6, 2022 Topic: Macroeconomic policy

In September 2021, I warned against inflation resulting from over ten years of ultra-soft monetary policies, in particular, the massive asset purchase programmes that have built up record-high central bank balance sheets. Expansionary fiscal policies have added to this build-up. Both the purchases and the policies have been continued for too long despite a change in the macroeconomic environment.

In 2020, advanced economy central banks reacted to COVID-19 similarly to the way they reacted to the global financial crisis of 2007-2009. They further intensified asset purchase programmes, despite the different characteristics of the crises. In 2020, a combination of demand-side and supply-side shocks created a temporary involuntary savings and monetary overhang. Because fiscal deficits and public debts increased during the pandemic, government bonds became the main assets absorbed by central banks.

Relaxation of lockdowns in 2021 led to an unfreezing of the monetary overhang. Continuation of expansionary monetary and fiscal policies through 2021 and, in some instances, into early 2022, added fuel to the fire.

Supply-side factors have also boosted inflation. Lockdowns disrupted global, regional and even local supply chains, eventually limiting the supply of certain critical goods and production inputs and contributing to their higher prices. The increasing tensions in the international trading system, such as the ongoing US-China trade conflict and various protectionist measures in response to the pandemic, have not helped eliminate production and supply bottlenecks.

Pandemic-induced structural changes produced similar effects. Some had a temporary character but others are permanent, such as the move to remote work, online trade and services. As a result, the demand for some goods and components, such as semiconductors, has increased above production capacities.

Finally, there have also been supply disruptions and associated price increases caused by the non-competitive character of some markets and by political factors. The rapid growth of the price of natural gas in Europe in 2021-2022 is a good example.

The war in Ukraine, sanctions against Russia, and Russia’s retaliatory measures have caused further increases in prices of energy (oil, oil products, natural gas, coal and electricity), food (especially grain, animal feed and cooking oil), metals, and several other inputs (including chemicals, fertilisers, timber, cement and steel and aluminium products).

However, some supply-side shocks (exogenous for a single national economy) have resulted from changes in global demand. For example, commodity prices increased in 2021 (Figure 2) because of a rapid economic recovery and increasing global demand. Between 2010 and 2013, high commodity prices did not lead to higher inflation because of demand constraints.

Central banks have been slow to react

In 2021, the US Federal Reserve Board (Fed) and European Central Bank (ECB) claimed that higher inflation had a temporary character and would disappear in 2022.

The Fed started to change its attitude and policies in November 2021. In December 2021, it accelerated the tapering of new asset purchases. In January 2022, it decided to stop increasing its asset holdings in March 2022. In March 2022, it increased the Federal Fund Rate (FFR) by 0.25 percentage points, followed by decisions to further increase the FFR by 0.50 pp (up to 1%) taken on 4 May 2022 and 0.75pp (up to 1.75%) on 15 June 2022. From 1 June 2022 it started to reduce its balance sheet.

The ECB has been slower. In March 2022, it terminated net asset purchases under the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme. However, the existing stock of assets will be rolled over until at least the end of 2024. Special conditions applicable under the third series of targeted longer-term refinancing operations (TLTRO III) ended in June 2022, and net purchases under the regular asset purchase programme ended on 1 July 2022, but the existing stock of assets will be reinvested. Finally, in July 2022 the ECB preannounced a 25 basis points interest rate hike. Overall, it looks like ECB monetary policy tightening will be gradual.

Risk of higher inflationary expectations

More than three decades of low inflation in a context of strengthened central bank independence have helped anchor low inflationary expectations in advanced economies. Now, this achievement may be lost because of:

  • The slow central bank response to the inflation surge in 2021 and 2022 and their misjudged opinions on the temporary character of inflation;
  • Changes in the Fed and ECB strategies, which are already tolerating inflation above 2% as compensation for past inflation below this level. This increases uncertainty about the timing and strength of their responses to higher inflation.
  • The increasing fiscal dependence of central banks in an environment of expansionary fiscal policies in most advanced economies.

After a more than a decade of quantitative easing, central banks’ balance sheets expanded and became dominated by government bonds on their asset side. Stopping inflation requires central banks to reduce their balance sheets and to hike interest rates. However, both actions will raise governments’ interest payments and further deteriorate their fiscal positions. It will lead to a conflict between central banks and governments, which may undermine central bank independence.

The monetary policy dependence on the fiscal situation is already visible in the euro area and may explain the ECB’s reluctance to start a tightening cycle. The yields on government bonds in the highly indebted euro-area countries were kept low thanks to the ECB’s asset purchase programmes and its interventions in the bond market when spreads increased. Such interventions have been justified by the ECB’s financial stability mandate with the declared goals of avoiding financial fragmentation in the euro area and smoothing the monetary policy transmission mechanism.

How to stop high inflation?

Disinflation requires both monetary and fiscal policy tightening. It should be done quickly to avoid building up inflationary inertia and a stagflation scenario, as happened in the 1970s.

Given high public debt levels and the increasing fiscal dependence of central banks, budgetary adjustment is even more urgent than monetary policy tightening. It would give monetary policy more room for manoeuvre and help defend central bank independence. Fiscal adjustment measures must be country-specific and, in most cases, should include both increases in revenue and reduced expenditure. Ideally, such measures should help address long-term development challenges. For example, higher retirement ages and green taxation could reduce fiscal deficits, mitigate the adverse effects of population aging and limit carbon emissions.

Fighting inflation in the environment of the adverse supply shocks must involve economic and social costs, but postponing disinflation or adopting half-measures will be even more costly. Governments should avoid populist measures such as price controls or direct or indirect subsidisation of those goods and services (for example, energy), for which prices are rising rapidly.

Recommended citation:

Dabrowski, M. (2022) ‘Central banks have been too slow in responding to higher inflation’, Opinion, 6 July


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint.

Due to copyright agreements we ask that you kindly email request to republish opinions that have appeared in print to [email protected].

Read article Download PDF More on this topic
 

Policy Contribution

An analysis of central bank decision-making

An earlier version of this paper was presented at ‘The MPC at 25’, a conference organised by the United Kingdom’s National Institute of Economic and Social Research, in London, 30 March 2022 The process by which central banks take decisions has evolved over the years, with a tendency towards independence and decisions taken by committees […]

By: Maria Demertzis, Catarina Martins and Nicola Viegi Topic: Banking and capital markets Date: July 11, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Blog Post

The implications for public debt of high inflation and monetary tightening

Expected increases in interest rates and reductions in real GDP growth rates will result in relatively small increases in public debt-to-GDP ratios, but inflation will reduce debt ratios very substantially

By: Zsolt Darvas Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: June 29, 2022
Read article Download PDF
 

External Publication

European governanceEuropean Parliament

Fragmentation risk in the euro area: no easy way out for the European Central Bank

The ECB should design a specific tool that will accompany interest rate hikes to neutralise the risk of fragmentation directly for countries facing it, staying within the bounds of the EU treaties and ensuring political legitimacy. We also advocate structural changes to the ECB’s collateral framework to avoid unnecessary uncertainty surrounding the safe asset status of European sovereign bonds.

By: Maria Demertzis, Grégory Claeys and Lionel Guetta-Jeanrenaud Topic: European governance, European Parliament, Testimonies Date: June 8, 2022
Read article More by this author
 

Opinion

European governance

Three headaches for the European Central Bank

Even though inflation in the euro area is lower than in the US, three issues make it a lot more difficult for the ECB to control inflation and preserve financial stability. Once again, the limits of EMU architecture are visible and will require a rethink.

By: Maria Demertzis Topic: European governance, Macroeconomic policy Date: May 31, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Podcast

Podcast

Taming inflation?

What are the implications of prolonged inflation?

By: The Sound of Economics Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 25, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

How are crises changing central bank doctrines?

How is monetary policy evolving in the face of recent crises? With central banks taking on new roles, how accountable are they to democratic institutions?

Speakers: Maria Demertzis, Benoît Coeuré, Pervenche Berès, Hans-Helmut Kotz and Athanasios Orphanides Topic: Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: May 11, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Opinion

The week inflation became entrenched

The events that have unfolded since 24 February have solved one dispute: inflation is no longer temporary.

By: Maria Demertzis Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: March 8, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Opinion

The weakness of average inflation targeting

Introducing average over time without defining what this means is counterproductive and current levels of inflation in the US will sooner or later expose this weakness in the Fed’s new strategy.

By: Maria Demertzis Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: February 22, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

A debate on fiscal rules and the new monetary strategy

Presentation of the Yearbook of the Euro 2022.

Speakers: Maria Demertzis, Fernando Fernández, Gonzalo García Andrés, José Carlos García de Quevedo, Pablo Hernández de Cos and Jorge Yzaguirre Topic: European governance Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: February 17, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Opinion

East-west divergence in central bank action will not last much longer

Fed shift towards raising rates will make it hard for China and Japan not to tighten monetary policy.

By: Alicia García-Herrero Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: February 16, 2022
Read article More by this author
 

Podcast

Podcast

Turkey’s economic struggles

Will inflation continue to surge?

By: The Sound of Economics Topic: Global economy and trade, Macroeconomic policy Date: January 26, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Opinion

Inflation ideology: camp permanent or camp temporary?

Policy focus should be on tackling uncertainties by being able to tackle as many scenarios as possible.

By: Maria Demertzis Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: December 9, 2021
Load more posts